How The FAA Is Keeping Flying Cars In Science Fiction – OpEd
By FEE
By Maxwell Tabarrok
Flying cars are used as a synecdoche for all of the 20th-century sci-fi dreams that never came true. But they shouldn’t be grouped with moon cities or Dyson spheres. Private, point-to-point aircraft as cheap as a Chevy Tahoe could have been available decades ago. We should have them by now and could have them soon with a few regulatory changes.
Many outright dismiss the idea of flying cars as impossible science fiction, but small, private, point-to-point aircraft are technologically possible and have been for nearly 100 years. Here is one prototype, the 1935 Pitcairn Autogiro, making a near-vertical landing on the National Mall while surrounded by a crowd and then driving to the Bureau of Air Commerce down the street. The fundamental physics and engineering of flying cars was not a constraint in the early 20th century, and it certainly isn’t now, as demonstrated by electric vertical-takeoff-and-landing (VTOL) aircraft like those made by Beta or Joby.
A working prototype is one thing, but the economic constraints are tougher. Carl Benz invented the first recognizable car in 1885, but its impact was relatively small until Ford started mass-manufacturing the Model T 40 years later. Here too, the flying car could have succeeded. The manufacturing of planes was on an exponential curve upwards starting in the ’40s through to the late ’70s, similar to the path that automobile manufacturing had taken 20 years earlier. In 1979, 18,000 general aviation aircraft were shipped, up from under 4,000 in 1950. A Ford Motors feasibility study of the market potential of Moulton Taylor’s Aerocar—one of the first practical flying cars—estimated likely production and sales of 25,000 units a year. A base model Cessna in 1980 cost about $20,000. If that nominal price had tracked overall inflation, it would be around $80,000 today. The supply-side economics of flying cars were surmountable and were on a clear path towards affordable mass-manufacturing.
The demand-side economics of flying cars weren’t a problem either. Beyond fulfilling the ancient human dream of flight, private, point-to-point aircraft are extremely economically valuable. There are more than 15,000 flights a year between Los Angeles and Las Vegas, with millions of passengers generating billions of dollars in revenue. At just over 200 miles, this is well within the range of small private aircraft, along with several of the other busiest domestic plane routes like Los Angeles to San Francisco, Honolulu to Kahului, Atlanta to Orlando, and New York to Boston. Private, point-to-point aircraft can fly these routes without the security lines or the last mile problem.
Perhaps the easiest way to understand the economic potential of private, point-to-point aircraft is to imagine having the labor market of Manhattan and the housing market of Allentown. Keeping the high wages of NYC without paying the high costs can easily increase your income by several tens of thousands of dollars per year. Expanding the effective radius of cities, quickening inter-city travel, and offering access to the inherent joy of flight would more than justify a luxury car-level price tag on a flying car for many Americans.
Despite dozens of successful prototypes over the past 100 years, early momentum in mass-manufacturing, and clear demand for the aircraft, flying cars never materialized, and the private aviation industry in general cratered to levels of production as low as those in the first decades of the airplane’s invention.
This massive gap in small aircraft manufacturing needs explanation. Air traffic congestion, the higher skill floor of flying, and energy prices are real constraints that would have made it difficult for private aviation to grow as fast as automobiles did, but they can’t explain a modern rate of production that’s 30 times lower than what it was in the ’70s.
Extraordinarily strict regulations on aircraft by the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA) are the clearest explanation for the absence of flying cars and the decline of aircraft manufacturing in general. There are thousands of pages of meticulous rules governing everything in the lifecycle of an aircraft, but some stand out as massive drivers of cost.
One is pilot training, where the FAA is a global outlier in requiring 1,500 instructor training hours compared to 250 in most other developed nations. Even the lower grades of pilot license can cost several tens of thousands of dollars. Another is the strict liability applied to aircraft. The national explosion of liability lawsuits in the US through the ’60s and ’70s hit aircraft manufacturers particularly hard. The industry’s liability insurance premiums increased by nearly ten times, from $24 million to $210 million, from 1978 to 1980. There are also strict requirements for maintenance approvals on all general aviation aircraft after every 100 hours of flight. The procedures required for this maintenance and the certifications required of the person maintaining it also comprise dozens of dense pages in the Code of Federal Regulations (CFR).
There are many other costly and unnecessary regulations on aircraft that have surely slowed their development. But none of these can fully explain the failure of flying cars. The section of the CFRdedicated to safety requirements for cars is longer than that for general aviation aircraft, and those regulations are not less meticulous in general.
By far the costliest part of the FAA’s regulation is not any particular standard imposed on pilot training, liability, or aircraft safety, but a slight shift in the grammatical tense of all these rules. The Department of Transportation (DOT) sets strict safety requirements for cars, but manufacturers are allowed to release new designs without first getting the DOT to sign off that all the requirements have been satisfied. The law is enforced ex post, and the government will impose recalls and fines when manufacturers fail to follow the law.
The FAA, by contrast, enforces all of its safety rules ex ante. Before aircraft manufacturers can do anything with a design, they have to get the FAA’s signoff, which can take more than a decade. This regulatory approach also makes the FAA far more risk-averse, since any problems with an aircraft after release are blamed on the FAA’s failure to catch them. With ex post enforcement, the companies that failed to follow the law would be blamed, and the FAA rewarded, for enforcing recall.
This subtle difference in the ordering of legal enforcement is the major cause of the stagnation of aircraft design and manufacturing.
In some ways, this is an optimistic message, since it illuminates an attractive political compromise: keep all of the safety standards on airplanes exactly as they are, but enforce these standards like they’re enforced with cars—i.e., through post-market surveillance, recall, and punishment. This small change would reinvigorate the general aviation industry, putting it back on the exponential trend upwards that it lost 50 years ago.
Restarting interest and innovation in small plane manufacturing would quickly lead to private, point-to-point aircraft coming onto the market. They would be expensive and clunky at first, just like the early cars of the 1930s. But competition and incremental improvements would quickly bring us to the 20th-century Jetsons dream that we should have fulfilled decades ago.
Flying cars are within our grasp; we just have to reach out and take them.
- About the author: Maxwell Tabarrok is an Economics and Math graduate from the University of Virginia and a blogger at Maximum Progress, which covers topics in economics, mathematics, philosophy, history, and technology.
- Source: This article was published by FEE
This article conveniently ignores two major impediments to the expansion of light aviation usage and instead conveniently blames this lack of expansion on the restrictive policies of the FAA. If the FAA was indeed to blame, then light aviation would have expanded in countries with more lax aviation requirements. This has not been the case.
The reality is light aviation as a commuter tool in lieu of a car is a flawed concept. In the heady days of early aviation these flaws were conveniently ignored. They are as follows:
Flying vehicles operate in a three-dimensional space, whereas cars operate in only two dimensions. The all too frequent fender bender will generally ruin one’s day in a car but will ruin one’s life in a flying vehicle.
Flying cars that flip between freeways and airways will never become a reality as a car must be built very differently to a plane. Cars are heavy, to facilitate safely withstanding impacts, flying vehicles need to focus on weight saving, to facilitate becoming airborne. Flying cars will therefore always be light, fragile, unstable and unsafe on a roadway.